Skip to main content
What policy reforms could simplify the tax code?
What policy reforms could simplify the tax code?

Reducing the number of distinctions among economic activities and taxpayers’ characteristics would simplify the code, reducing both taxpayers’ compliance costs and governmental administrative costs. Some distinctions among taxpayers promote fairness, so there are trade-offs among goals, but the tax law could be simplified without compromising equity. Clarifying some tax rules would limit the ability of sophisticated taxpayers from strategically exploiting ambiguities in the tax code to their advantage.

The key to tax simplification is to make fewer distinctions across economic activities and taxpayers’ characteristics. This would not only reduce compliance costs, but would also allow for simpler administration. For example, allowing taxpayers who itemize their deductions to deduct charitable contributions requires administrative resources to determine which organizations are eligible to receive charitable contributions, and to ensure that taxpayers make the contributions they claim on their tax returns. This also imposes record-keeping costs on taxpayers.

A simple tax system would generally be structured with a broad tax base with rates that are the same across different income sources or types of expenditure. Progressivity could be embodied in the rate structure (with rates rising with income, as they do now), a basic exemption amount, and the choice of tax base (income, consumption, or another measure), rather than through specific provisions that treat different levels of income and consumption differently. Universal exemptions, deductions, or credits are much simpler to administer than targeted ones.

The tax law could be made even simpler if all income were taxed at a single rate. Then, all taxes on earnings, interest, and dividends could be collected by withholding from employers and financial institutions without many taxpayers needing to file returns. But such a tax system would conflict with the goal of progressivity—imposing higher tax rates on those with a greater ability to pay—and many would regard that as unfair.

Some other provisions that add complexity are nonetheless necessary for tax fairness and economic efficiency. For example, self-employed taxpayers who use a personal automobile in their business must keep records to distinguish between personal and business uses of their car. Nonetheless, a fair and efficient income tax requires that business costs should be deductible, while personal consumption expenses should not.

Several modest changes could make the current tax system simpler without compromising fairness or reducing incentives to work, save, and invest. One option would be to coordinate the phaseout of tax credits. Specific tax credits phase out across different income ranges, so that claiming each credit requires a separate worksheet and tax calculation. The phaseouts also create hidden taxes over the phaseout range and diminish the credits’ effectiveness in encouraging the activities they are designed to spur.

Numerous provisions—each with its own rules—apply to the same general activity. Coordinating or consolidating these provisions could simplify tax-return preparation and reduce tax-planning costs with little or no change in revenue or the distribution of tax burdens. Examples include the various provisions related to families with children (the earned income tax credit, the dependent credit, and the child credit), tax subsidies for education (the American Opportunity and Lifetime Learning credits, and the deductibility of tuition and fees), and saving incentives (traditional individual retirement accounts, Roth IRAs, education IRAs, and Keogh plans).

Yet another simplification would tax capital gains at the same rate as ordinary income in return for reduced top tax rates. This was a main feature of the 1986 Tax Reform Act, although the 1986 reform also retained a limitation on capital losses to prevent selective realization of losses by taxpayers with gains on their investment portfolios. Returning to this approach would reduce incentives for complex tax-planning strategies that recharacterize ordinary income as capital gain. Yet a higher capital gains rate would increase incentives to delay or wholly avoid realizations of capital gains and put new pressure on rules, such as those for like-kind exchanges, that define when a realization event has occurred.

Even the most skilled and experienced examiners will struggle to enforce tax laws that are ambiguous at their core. In those cases, audits are no substitute for clarity in the tax laws. This point is most evident with passthrough entities (e.g., partnerships and S corporations), for which current statutes practically invite taxpayers to adopt aggressive reporting positions—some challenged by examiners, some accepted as legal avoidance strategies, and some that are never observed because audits at the passthrough-entity level are rare. Congress could write better tax rules for passthrough entities that would make the IRS’s task much easier and would make enforcement more equitable. Some examples of tax laws that would achieve those goals include repealing the deduction for qualified business income, abolishing partnership special allocations and requiring partnerships to allocate tax items in proportion to capital interests, and applying the self-employment tax to the distributive-share income of active S corporation shareholders.

Updated January 2024
Further reading

Berger, Daniel, Victoria Bryant, John Guyton, and Patrick Langetieg. 2017. “Estimating the Effects of Tax Reform on Compliance Burdens.” 2017 IRS Research Bulletin, 179-190. Washington, DC: Internal Revenue Service.

Gale, William G. 2007. ”Fixing the Tax System: Support Fairer Simpler, and More Adequate Taxation.” Opportunity 08 Paper. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

Gale, William G. 2009. “Remove the Return.” Tax Analysts. September 9.

Hemel, Daniel, Janet Holtzblatt, and Steve Rosenthal. 2022. “The Tax Gap’s Many Shades of Gray.” Washington, DC: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center.

Joint Committee on Taxation. 2015. ”Complexity in the Federal Tax System.” JCX-49-15. Washington, DC: Joint Committee on Taxation.

Maag, Elaine. 2011. “Tax Simplification: Clarifying Work, Child, and Education Incentives.” Washington, DC: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center.

Nunns, James, Elaine Maag, and Hang Nguyen. 2016. “An Option to Reform the Income Tax Treatment of Families and Work.” Washington, DC: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center.

National Taxpayer Advocate. 2020. National Taxpayer Advocate 2020 Purple Book: Compilation of Legislative Recommendations to Strengthen Taxpayer Rights and Improve Tax Administration. Washington, DC: Internal Revenue Service.

Steuerle, C. Eugene. 1999. “Candidates for Tax Simplification Reform.” Tax Analysts. July 12.

Steuerle, C. Eugene. 2015. “One Avenue to Bipartisan Tax Reform: Simplification and Improved Tax Administration.” TaxVox (blog). April 8.

US Senate Committee on Finance. 2015. “Tax Complexity, Compliance, and Administration: The Merits of Simplification in Tax Reform.” Hearing of the US Senate Committee on Finance, Washington, DC, March 10.

Income tax (individual)
What are the benefits of simpler taxes?